4. Does LGBTI+ equality pay?

LGBTI+ inclusion is a question of human rights, but it also makes a lot of economic sense. Ending discrimination against LGBTI+ Americans and creating inclusive environments and opportunities in and outside the labour market not only means that LGBTI+ Americans can get their fair share, but also that there are more goods and services being produced in the economy, and more income to spend and to save or invest, thus benefiting all of society. The lack of a strong evidence-based economic case for LGBTI+ inclusion is a barrier to further progressing in social acceptance of LGBTI+ individuals, and thus to expanding legal and lived equality for this population (OECD, 2020[1]): informing people, companies, and policy makers about the economic gains of LGBTI+ inclusion increases their support for LGBTI+ equality, including in countries where anti-LGBTI+ prejudice is widespread (Aksoy et al., 2022[2]).

This chapter aims to fill the gap by providing an evaluation of some of the economic returns of levelling the playing field for LGBTI+ individuals in the United States. It begins by exploring the potential increase in GDP that could result from closing LGBTI+ labour market gaps, drawing on the OECD long-term model. It then contextualises these figures by discussing several additional benefits that are not captured by this model but that could emerge from eliminating anti-LGBTI+ discrimination. The chapter concludes by quantifying the economic and well-being burden of mental health disparities among LGBTI+ individuals.

Unequal labour market success for LGBTI+ adults not only contradicts the moral imperative of equality in society, but it also entails significant economic costs by preventing LGBTI+ adults from realising their full productive potential, as shown in the previous chapters. In particular, employment discrimination against LGBTI+ workers leads to an underutilisation of existing human capital and to a misallocation of talents as LGBTI+ individuals are passed over in hiring and in career advancement. As a result, some LGBTI+ workers end up unemployed or in lower-skilled positions than they would otherwise be able to occupy. These detrimental consequences of discrimination might be amplified by negative feedback effects from the labour supply to the extent that reduced labour market prospects undermine incentives to participate in the labour force and productivity at work. These harmful repercussions on LGBTI+ individuals’ labour supply and productivity are further compounded by anti-LGBTI+ discrimination (in and outside the labour market) undermining the health of LGBTI+ individuals.

To evaluate the economic benefits of discontinuing these mechanisms, this section relies on the OECD long-term model (Guillemette and Turner, 2021[3]; Guillemette and Turner, 2018[4]). It begins by succinctly explaining how the model works, before outlining the features of the baseline scenario used to predict GDP. Subsequently, the section presents estimates of the average annual extra GDP that result from departing from the baseline, by closing unexplained labour market gaps between LGBTI+ and their cisgender straight peers. The section concludes with an examination of prior attempts to quantify the economic costs associated with anti-LGBTI+ discrimination.

The OECD long-term model is a tool employed by the OECD not only to project GDP trends up to 2060 for its member countries but also to quantify the economic returns of greater inclusion of marginalised groups. The model has already been used by the OECD on two notable occasions: first, to assess the benefits of enhanced labour market participation among older individuals across various OECD countries (OECD, 2020[5]), and second, to analyse the economic gains from achieving gender equality in the labour market (OECD, 2023[6]; OECD, 2022[7])

In this model, economic output Y in a given year t is measured based on a Cobb-Douglas production function. This production function has the advantage of presenting a great deal of realism as it is consistent with three economic stylised facts, i.e. patterns that hold true in various economies and times (see Box 4.1 for an overview).

More precisely, the Cobb-Douglas production function on which the OECD long-term model is grounded features three main factors: physical capital stock (Kt), total employment – or, equivalently, total number of workers – denoted by Nt, and labour productivity per worker (At). Specifically, we adapt the model to categorise the population of workers into two groups: cisgender straight individuals (CS) and LGBTI+ individuals. In alignment with the initial version of the model, we further divide each of these groups by sex assigned at birth (AMAB or AFAB) and by age group, which includes young (15-34), prime age (35-54), and mature (55-74) individuals.

Against this backdrop, GDP in year t is given by:

Yt=Kt13AtCS*NtCS+AtLGBTI+*NtLGBTI+23,

where AtCS and NtCS is the productivity per worker and the number of workers within the cisgender straight population, while AtLGBTI+and NtLGBTI+ is the productivity per worker and the number of workers within the LGBTI+ population.1

The key assumption in the baseline scenarios is the absence of a reduction in unexplained labour market gaps between LGBTI+ individuals and their cisgender straight peers. This assumption indicates a stagnation in the progress towards greater inclusion of LGBTI+ individuals.

The OECD long-term model offers a framework to quantify the additional GDP, compared to a baseline, that could result from bridging the unexplained gaps in employment and labour productivity for LGBTI+ individuals. The underlying assumption is that anti-LGBTI+ discrimination prevents them from reaching their full employment and labour productivity potential.

Specifically, the baseline scenarios are grounded in a set of long-run projections that pertain to key model parameters, namely total employment, labour productivity per worker, and capital stock (Guillemette and Turner, 2021[3]). The projections for total employment (Nt) are influenced by trends in the size and sex/age composition of the working-age population, according to United Nations population projections. They are also shaped by trends in employment rates across different sex/age groups, with a cohort approach applied to cyclically adjusted historical employment rates. Beyond these standard dynamics, which are integral to the initial version of the OECD long-term model, we introduce an innovation. We differentiate between total employment for cisgender straight adults and LGBTI+ adults, possibly further breaking down the data by sex and age group. This differentiation is based on the proportion of self-identified LGBTI+ adults within the total population, as well as on the demographic-adjusted employment disparities between LGBTI+ individuals and their cisgender straight peers. The results associated with these two dimensions are summarised in columns 1 and 2 of Table 4.1, based on the analysis performed in Chapters 2 and 3.

Regarding the projections for labour productivity per worker (At), we refine the initial version of the OECD long-term model by disaggregating labour productivity by LGBTI+ status, possibly differentiating by sex and age group. This estimation is informed by gaps in household income for employed individuals living alone, comparing LGBTI+ adults with their cisgender straight peers, and adjusting for essential demographic characteristics, as well as sector and occupation. These income disparities are presented in column 3 of Table 4.1, based on the estimates obtained in Chapter 3.

Finally, the projections for capital stock (Kt) rely on the assumption that the capital-to-output ratio will remain constant from 2024 onwards. This assumption implies that firms proportionally adapt their capital stock in response to changes in labour input. Although this approach abstracts from the dynamic adjustment of the capital stock, it is noteworthy that fluctuations in the capital-to-output ratio have had a relatively minor impact on economic growth in the United States over the past few decades (Jones, 2016[9]). In line with this prior research, our estimates of the economic gains of greater LGBTI+ inclusion remain virtually unchanged if we allow for fluctuations in the capital-to-output ratio.2

Specifically, we consider two distinct baseline scenarios:

  • A sex- and cohort-blind approach. This approach is considered naïve as it fails to account for variations in both the share of self-identified LGBTI+ individuals and their unexplained labour market disparities across different sexes and cohorts. It assumes that in 2024, the share of LGBTI+ individuals and their unexplained labour market disparities in each sex and age group is equal to their average in the total working-age population, as reported in Table 4.1, maintaining these averages static through 2060. With this baseline scenario, the GDP is projected to increase by 1.5% by the year 2060, assuming LGBTI+ equality is achieved by that time, which coincides with the last year of the OECD long-term model.

  • A cohort approach. This approach is deemed realistic as it recognises that both the share of self-identified LGBTI+ individuals and the extent of their labour market disparities differ by sex and cohort. This method assumes that for each sex and age group in 2024, the percentage of LGBTI+ adults and the degree of their labour market disparities remain unchanged as individuals in this group age. For instance, if AFAB LGBTI+ individuals aged 20 in 2024 experience a 12.8% lower labour productivity than their cisgender straight peers, as specified in Table 4.1, this gap is expected to still be equal to 12.8% as they age to 56 by the year 2060 (while the share of LGBTI+ individuals among the AFAB population aged 55-74 will then be equal to their share in the AFAB population aged 15-34 in 2024). With this baseline scenario, the GDP is projected to increase by 2.9% by the year 2060, provided that LGBTI+ equality is achieved by that time.

An additional baseline scenario could be envisioned that relies on a life-cycle approach. However, although this approach recognises that both the share of self-identified LGBTI+ individuals and the extent of their labour market disparities differ by sex and cohort, it is not a realistic method as it concomitantly assumes that these shares and disparities change as individuals in each group age. This assumption is at odd with Chapter 2. According to Chapter 2, the rising proportion of young adults identifying as LGBTI+ is not driven by an age effect, which would entail that, for younger generations, self-identifying as LGBTI+ is a fad that ceases once they grow older. Despite its lack of realism, we analyse the economic consequences of closing labour market gaps for LGBTI+ individuals under the life-cycle approach in Annex 1.A and find that closing unexplained labour market gaps for LGBTI+ individuals under this approach would still generate significant GDP gains.

For each of the two baseline scenarios described in the previous section, we consider that convergence towards LGBTI+ equality is achieved either in 2030, 2040 or 2050. Specifically, we assume that the employment rates and labour productivity of LGBTI+ adults converge linearly with those of their cisgender straight peers by these different time horizons. This entails that efforts are made every year until full equality between cisgender straight and LGBTI+ workers is achieved by the target year, with a particular emphasis on eradicating anti-LGBTI+ hiring discrimination and the misallocation of LGBTI+ talents. The assumption of convergence by 2030 is crafted based on the principles of the Agenda 2030 for Sustainable Development, ratified by the United Nations General Assembly in September 2015 (UN General Assembly, 2015[10]). Although LGBTI+ individuals are not explicitly categorised as a marginalised group in Agenda 2030, many of the 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) offer avenues to ensure that they are not left behind (Open for Business, 2020[11]; Stonewall International, 2016[12]). For instance, SDG 8 establishes that everyone has the right to employment and decent work, in a safe environment, with equal pay for work of equal value. By 2030, its objective is to attain full and productive employment for all women and men, including for young people and persons with disabilities.

Panel A of Figure 4.1 illustrates the GDP gain that would be generated from efforts to achieve LGBTI+ equality by 2030, 2040, and 2050, compared to the baseline scenario, when one relies on the sex- and cohort-blind approach. This means that the share of LGBTI+ individuals and their unexplained labour market disparities does not vary by sex and age group at the beginning of the period (2024), matching the average for the total working-age population.

Under these conditions, the United States could anticipate an increase in GDP equal to approximately 1.5% of the baseline GDP by 2030. Pushing this goal further would translate into the same increase in GDP by 2040 and 2050. To put an estimate of 1.5% of the baseline GDP into perspective, this amount is 40% higher than the total US expenditure on public unemployment and labour market programmes in 2020/21. It is also equivalent to 20% of pension spending in 2020 and to more than 6% of total social spending in 2021.3

The economic benefits of achieving LGBTI+ equality would be more substantial under a cohort approach (Panel B of Figure 4.1). There are two reasons for this. First, consistent with Chapter 2’s findings, such an approach accounts for the expected rise over time in the proportion of self-identified LGBTI+ individuals within the total population, as the younger cohorts, characterised by a larger share of non-heterosexual non-cisgender individuals, age. Second, it assumes that, as these younger cohorts mature, the extent of labour market disparities, which are more pronounced within this group, presumably due to a lower tendency for non-disclosure bias, would increase in the baseline scenario.

Under the cohort approach, the GDP is projected to increase by 1.6%, 2.1%, and 2.6% of the baseline GDP by 2030, 2040, and 2050, respectively. These projections assume that the United States achieves LGBTI+ equality by these respective time horizons.

As indicated in Table 4.2, attaining LGBTI+ equality by 2030 would result in an average annual increase in GDP of approximately 0.2% under the two approaches, which amounts to 10% of the average annual US GDP growth observed between 2013 and 2023. However, as already evident in Figure 4.1, delaying the achievement of LGBTI+ equality would yield reduced economic benefits when translated in yearly GDP gains. The average annual increase in GDP ranges between 0.09% and 0.13% if the target year is 2040, and between 0.06% and 0.10% if the target year is 2050.

The OECD long-term model offers a significant advantage by extending GDP projections up to 2060. This provides a tangible forecast of the economic benefits that can be realised by narrowing labour market disparities affecting LGBTI+ individuals across different time frames. Unlike static models, which do not account for the incremental nature of such changes, this dynamic model reinforces the economic argument for LGBTI+ equality with realistic projections, acknowledging that such equality cannot be achieved overnight.

However, this model can also be used in a static capacity to estimate the cost of not closing employment and labour productivity penalties faced by LGBTI+ individuals or, conversely, the gain associated with closing those gaps immediately. When used in this way, it reveals that instantaneously achieving LGBTI+ equality results in a GDP gain equivalent to approximately 1%, irrespective of the baseline scenario considered. Here, we assume that capital does not adjust, a reasonable assumption when the increase in labour input is assumed to be instantaneous.

There have been several previous attempts to quantify the immediate economic cost of LGBTI+ labour market gaps. The first comprehensive framework for assessing this burden was developed by Lee Badgett in 2014 (Badgett, 2014[13]) – see Box 4.2 for more details on the methodology. This framework is equivalent to a static version of the OECD long-term model, except that Badgett only considers the costs associated with lower labour productivity for employed LGBTI+ individuals, overlooking the impact of their lower employment rates. Badgett subsequently applied this framework with data from India and the Philippines (Badgett, 2020[14]). This seminal work laid the groundwork for subsequent analyses in this field, such as in South Africa (Nyek et al., 2019[15]), Kenya (Open for Business, 2019[16]), Czechia (Open for Business, 2020[17]), Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Ukraine (Open for Business, 2021[18]), and in the English-speaking Caribbean area (Open for Business, 2021[19]).

An interesting alternative to the static version of the OECD long-term model is a methodology developed by the International Labour Organization (ILO). This approach aims to quantify the economic output lost due to discrimination, as self-reported by affected individuals. Initially, this method was applied to study the economic impact of discrimination against people with disabilities (Buckup, 2009[20]) – see Box 4.3 for more details. However, this approach has its drawbacks. It is not based on a growth model, which can make it seem ad hoc. Additionally, using perceived discrimination as a proxy for actual discrimination can be problematic because the two can differ significantly, potentially leading to inaccurate estimates of the economic repercussions of discrimination.

The empirical application of ILOs’ methodology also poses challenges. It typically requires the collection of original survey data since few nationally representative surveys provide comprehensive information on both labour market outcomes and perceptions of discrimination. Two recent World Bank reports have attempted to apply the ILO’s methodology to quantify the economic cost of anti-LGBTI+ discrimination in the context of the Republic of Serbia (Flores et al., 2023[21]) and the Republic of North Macedonia (Flores et al., 2023[22]). However, these studies rely on data collected from a non-probability sample of LGBTI+ individuals. Specifically, these individuals were recruited through purposive methods, such as social media campaigns, and seem to come from the more privileged segments of the LGBTI+ population, leading to a selection bias that obscures any labour market disparities. Notably, they have a much higher educational attainment than the general population, which implies the presence of other unobserved traits conducive to economic success. Consequently, even when researchers control for demographic differences between the LGBTI+ sample and the general population, several of the gaps observed in terms of labour productivity, unemployment rate, or inactivity rate appear as premiums, not penalties, for LGBTI+ individuals. This selection bias leads to underestimating the economic cost of anti-LGBTI+ discrimination. Nevertheless, the World Bank provides estimates of the output lost due to the exclusion of LGBTI+ individuals which are economically significant: 0.5% of the 2021 GDP, both in Serbia and in the Republic of North Macedonia.

Eliminating anti-LGBTI+ discrimination will lead not only to closing labour market gaps between LGBTI+ individuals and their cisgender straight peers but also to significant additional gains that the OECD long-term model does not account for. This means that the actual economic benefits of increased LGBTI+ equality are likely to be even more substantial than the previous calculations suggest. In this section, we first explore the primary channels through which ending anti-LGBTI+ discrimination can drive additional economic gains. We then discuss other potential channels which, although less apparent, can still have far-reaching effects in terms of economic growth.

Promoting greater LGBTI+ equality leads to production gains that subsequently bolster public finances. An uptick in production and labour earnings enhances public revenue from corporation tax, income tax, and social security contributions. These positive effects might be further magnified by increased consumption tax revenue, at least in the short run. As detailed in Box 4.4 and shown in Figure 4.2, LGBT individuals spend more on consumer goods and services than their cisgender straight peers, controlling for essential demographics, including parental status. This pattern could possibly be in response to the uneven playing field they navigate, meaning that the distinctive consumption trends of LGBT individuals might vanish as they experience a more level playing field. Moreover, eradicating anti-LGBTI+ discrimination cuts public expenditure, as greater workforce participation reduces the need for unemployment benefits, active labour market policies, and social transfers.

Promoting greater LGBTI+ equality can also lead to economic benefits through reduced public health expenditures. As discussed in Chapter 3, stigma has been identified as a significant factor contributing to the poorer mental, behavioural, and physical health of LGBTI+ individuals. The financial implications could be substantial. In 2022, the United States spent 16.6% of its GDP to healthcare services (OECD, 2023[25]). This spending covered personal healthcare – which includes curative, rehabilitative, long-term care, ancillary services, and medical goods – as well as collective services such as prevention, public health services, and health administration. Furthermore, reducing stigma-related health issues for LGBTI+ individuals would not only alleviate the burden on the health system but also lessen associated costs in other areas, like social security programmes, which cover paid sick leave and disability benefits. It is critical to note that these expenditure figures do not reflect the broader costs associated with the negative impact of discrimination on health, such as the loss of human capital due to the premature mortality of LGBTI+ individuals whose health suffers due to stigma, including through deaths by suicide.4 In Section 4.4, we aim to address this limitation by closely examining the economic and well-being burden that health disparities impose on LGBTI+ individuals.

Beyond bolstering tax revenues and reducing public expenditures, eliminating anti-LGBTI+ discrimination will bring significant economic benefits through various additional channels. These include enhanced wealth accumulation, greater opportunities for LGBTI+ individuals to start families and invest in their children, and the potential to tap into the diversity and gender equality dividend.

Marriage equality for LGBTI+ individuals is likely to boost their capacity for wealth accumulation thanks to a stabilizing effect that facilitates long-term planning (Badgett, 2009[26]). Evidence has confirmed this mechanism, by revealing the benefits for same-sex couples of being able to “upgrade” their civil partnership to a civil marriage, even in countries like the Netherlands where civil partnership and civil marriage are fully similar in terms of rights and obligations. More precisely, same-sex partners who transformed their civil partnership into marriage had a substantially lower separation rate following this change than similar partners who stayed in a civil partnership, which suggests that the symbolism of marriage is real and contributes to the longevity of same-sex partnerships (Chen and van Ours, 2020[27]). In line with this finding, (Delhommer and Hamermesh, 2021[28]) highlighted the economic benefits of marriage based on US data. Their research compared two otherwise observationally identical same-sex couples with the same duration of partnership and found that the couple who experienced a longer period of their relationship under the institution of legalised same-sex marriage had a higher household income and were more likely to own a home.

Greater equality for LGBTI+ individuals in other life areas is likely to further enhance their potential to accumulate wealth. For example, reduced barriers to parenthood can lead to increased savings. Additionally, ending the discrimination that LGBTI+ individuals face in credit and mortgage lending (see Chapter 3 for evidence of such discrimination) can significantly improve their financial health.

Lowering barriers to assisted reproductive technology for LGBTI+ individuals is likely to foster fertility. This is a promising perspective in a context where OECD countries are currently exhibiting the lowest ever recorded average fertility rate – at only 1.59 children per woman in 2020, which is far below the “replacement level” of 2.1 children per woman (Fluchtmann, van Veen and Adema, 2023[29]). In other words, greater LGBTI+ equality could help to counteract the shrinking working-age population occurring in several OECD countries, a trend resulting from rising longevity and falling fertility rates. Simultaneously, providing LGBTI+ individuals with greater access to adoption and foster care will lead to increased investment in children, as more children without biological parents able to care for them will have the opportunity to grow up in a loving and caring family.

This increased investment in children will likely be compounded by more LGBTI+ individuals becoming biological parents through assisted reproductive technology. Indeed, compelling evidence indicates that children of same-sex parents conceived through these methods tend to have better education and health outcomes compared to the biological children of different-sex parents (OECD, 2020[1]). This finding remains consistent even when considering differences in socio-economic status between same-sex and different-sex parents, as same-sex parents who procreate typically have higher levels of income and education than their different-sex counterparts – an expected result due to the significant time and financial costs associated with assisted reproductive technology. In line with the observed education and health advantages of children born to same-sex couples, same-sex parents tend to spend more time with their children than different-sex parents. In the United States, women (regardless of their partners’ sex) and partnered gay men engage in a similar amount of child-focused time with children (roughly 100 minutes per day). By contrast, partnered heterosexual men dedicate less than one hour to their children, on average (Prickett, Martin-Storey and Crosnoe, 2015[30]). The education and health premium observed in children of same-sex parents who were conceived through assisted reproductive technology may reflect that same-sex couples cannot unintentionally become parents due to birth control failure, as can happen with heterosexual couples. Instead, they deliberately choose to become parents. This dynamic may lead to a selection effect where gays and lesbians who become parents are, on average, more committed to the challenges of parenting compared to some of their heterosexual counterparts (Rosenfeld, 2010[31]).

Ending anti-LGBTI+ discrimination can equip the economy to harness the economic potential of greater diversity. A work environment that is inclusive creates the condition for diversity to become a performance enhancer – while diversity can hinder performance in non-inclusive settings (OECD, 2020[32]). An inclusive environment allows for the pooling of a richer set of perspectives, skills and experiences whose benefits can outweigh the increased communication and co-ordination costs associated with diverse backgrounds.

Dutch researchers have corroborated this mechanism, using a sample of 550 students from Amsterdam University of Applied Sciences, known for its commitment to attracting a diverse range of profiles eager to engage with peers from different backgrounds. In line with this mission, the student pool analysed has an almost equal split by gender and foreign-born/native-born status. Specifically, students of foreign origin make up 55% of the sample, with a significant proportion hailing from non-European countries (excluding North America, Australia, and New Zealand). As a component of their training, students form teams of 10 to 12 to create and manage a real company over a year. Each team handles fundraising, production, marketing, accounting, tax obligations, and more. To assess the impact of diversity, the researchers determined each team’s composition, exogenously varying not only the gender proportion (from 20% to 60%) but also the mix of nationalities. Their findings indicate that both gender diversity (Hoogendoorn, Oosterbeek and van Praag, 2013[33]) and racial/ethnic diversity (Hoogendoorn and van Praag, 2018[34]) significantly boost the turnover and profit of the student-led start-ups, an outcome likely influenced by the inclusive environment in which students operate. Of course, further research is needed to test whether these findings apply to settings with a diversity of sexual orientations and gender identities.

The positive impacts of greater diversity in sexual orientations and gender identities, especially in environments where such diversity is valued, can be amplified by the ripple effects that greater LGBTI+ equality might have on the emancipation of other groups, primarily women. LGBTI+ inclusion inherently challenges heteronormativity, which confines men and women to rigid roles that are obstructive to women’s empowerment. Furthermore, embracing LGBTI+ identities means recognising the complex spectrum of gender, leading to a re-evaluation of societal expectations for both men and women. In line with this observation, countries most proactive in enacting laws that promote LGBTI+ equality also tend to have the highest support for gender equality and female labour force participation. Additionally, these countries often exhibit the narrowest gender wage gaps (OECD, 2020[1]). Under these circumstances, the elimination of anti-LGBTI+ discrimination might bolster gender equality which, alone, has proven to generate substantial economic gains (OECD, 2023[6]; OECD, 2022[7]).

The purpose of this section is to quantify the economic and well-being burden faced by LGBTI+ individuals due to their disproportionate health challenges. This burden can be thought of as comprising three main components: i) the reduction in market income; ii) the reduction in longevity; and iii) the reduction in psychological well-being, often labelled as “pain and suffering” (World Health Organization, 2001[35]). The reduction in market income encompasses at least four sub-components. First, the private costs of medical treatment – public health expenditures which are discussed in Section 4.3. are not considered here as the focus is the direct burden borne by LGBTI+ individuals. Second, the loss of labour-market income due to morbidity, a factor accounted for by the OECD long-term model. Third, the diminished adult earning power resulting from diseases in childhood. And fourth, the loss of future earnings attributable to premature mortality.

This section first presents the methodological framework used to measure the economic and well-being burdens that LGBTI+ Americans face due to their health disparities. It then applies this methodology, focusing on the lower mental health of LGBTI+ individuals. In this setting, the estimates provided offer only a partial analysis of the full impact of their health disparities which often extend to behavioural health issues like sleep disorders and substance abuse, as well as physical health problems, including cardiovascular diseases and certain cancers.5

Applied to the mental health disparities of LGBTI+ individuals, the methodological framework developed by the World Health Organization entails three main steps.

  1. 1. Estimating the additional risk for LGBTI+ individuals to exhibit generalised anxiety or major depressive disorder. This initial step comprises three stages:

    1. a. Determining the higher prevalence of these conditions among LGBTI+ individuals by calculating the percentage difference in the likelihood of exhibiting symptoms between LGBTI+ individuals and their cisgender straight peers, while accounting for differences in demographics and household income across these two groups, based on HPS data.

    2. b. Calculating the increased number of LGBTI+ individuals with these conditions by applying the percentage difference obtained in the previous stage to the population of LGBTI+ individuals aged 15 or older. This figure is based on the proportion of LGBTI+ people in this age group, as derived from HPS data.

    3. c. Assessing the proportion of LGBTI+ individuals with these conditions within the overall affected population by dividing the number from the previous stage by the total number of people affected by these conditions, as derived from HPS data.

  2. 2. Computing the number of disability-adjusted life years (DALYs) due to the higher prevalence of generalised anxiety or major depressive disorder among LGBTI+ individuals by multiplying the estimate from the last stage of Step 1 by the average number of DALYs in the total population attached to these conditions. Specifically, this number captures the cumulative years of life that people with at least one of these conditions lose from an early death or from poorer quality of life. It is obtained by adding the impact that these conditions have in terms of number of years of life lost (YLLs) and number of years lived with a disability (YLDs).6 The average number of DALYs in the total population associated with generalised anxiety and major depressive disorders is obtained from the Global Burden of Diseases, Injuries, and Risk Factors Study 2019 (GBD, 2019[36]) which provides a 95% confidence interval for the number of DALYs related to 369 diseases and injuries, in 204 countries and territories.

  3. 3. Converting the mental health-related burdens of LGBTI+ individuals into a GDP percentage loss. To estimate the cost of these burdens on the economy, we draw on the World Health Organization’s Commission on Macroeconomics and Health guidelines (World Health Organization, 2001[35]). Based on estimates of individual’s willingness to pay for an improvement in their health risk, these recommendations assert that the value of an extra year of healthy life – because of successfully treating a disease, for example – is worth much more than just the additional market income earned in that year. In fact, it suggests that a healthy year can be valued at up to three times an individual’s annual earnings, considering not only market consumption but also the value of leisure, the intrinsic value of longevity, and the avoidance of the sufferings associated with illness. Utilising this approach, we calculate a range for the economic cost:

    1. a. The lower bound is the total DALYs related to anxiety and depression multiplied by the GDP per capita – this represents the direct economic impact.

    2. b. The upper bound is this same figure but multiplied by three times the GDP per capita – reflecting the broader value of health beyond earning capacity.

Each result is then expressed as a percentage of total GDP, providing a scale for the economic and well-being impact of mental health disparities among LGBTI+ individuals.

Lee Badgett was the first to adapt the methodology developed by the World Health Organization to the disproportionate health challenges for LGBTI+ individuals (Badgett, 2014[13]). Since then, this method has been applied to the context of South Africa (Nyek et al., 2019[15]), Kenya (Open for Business, 2019[16]), India and the Philippines (Badgett, 2020[14]), Czechia (Open for Business, 2020[17]), Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Ukraine (Open for Business, 2021[18]), the English-speaking Caribbean area (Open for Business, 2021[19]), and Uzbekistan (Open for Business, 2021[37]).

We add to this literature by focusing on the US context. The economic and well-being impact of mental health disparities among LGBTI+ Americans is substantial. In 2024, it will amount to a loss which, expressed as a share of GDP, varies between 0.04% (lower bound) and 0.12% (upper bound) of US GDP, or between USD 11.2 billion and USD 33.6 billion (Figure 4.3). In terms of magnitude, this cost is equivalent to 4%-12% of US expenditure on incapacity (spending due to sickness, disability and occupational injury) in 2020 (OECD, 2023[38]).

References

[2] Aksoy, C. et al. (2022), Reducing Sexual-Orientation Discrimination: Experimental Evidence from Basic Information Treatments, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management.

[14] Badgett, M. (2020), The Economic Case for LGBT Equality: why fair and equal treatment benefits us all, Boston, Massachusetts: Beacon Press.

[13] Badgett, M. (2014), The Economic Cost of Stigma and the Exclusion of LGBT People: A Case Study of India, Washington, D.C. : World Bank Group, http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/527261468035379692/The-economic-cost-of-stigma-and-the-exclusion-of-LGBT-people-a-case-study-of-India.

[26] Badgett, M. (2009), “The Economic Value of Marriage for Same-Sex Couples”, Drake L. Rev., 58, 1081.

[39] Banks, C. (2001), The Cost of Homophobia: Literature Review of the Economic Impact of Homophobia in Canda, CUISR: Community - Univesity Institute for Social Research.

[20] Buckup, S. (2009), ““The Price of Exclusion: The Economic Consequences of Excluding People with Disabilities from the World of Work”, Employment Sector Working Paper 43 (Geneva: International Labour Organization, 2009)..

[27] Chen, S. and J. van Ours (2020), “Symbolism matters: The effect of same-sex marriage legalization on partnership stability”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 178, pp. 44-58, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2020.07.021.

[28] Delhommer, S. and D. Hamermesh (2021), “Same‐Sex Couples and the Gains to Marriage: The Importance of the Legal Environment”, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., vol. 40(4), pages 1120-1139, September., https://doi.org/10.1002/pam.22287.

[22] Flores, A. et al. (2023), “The Economic Cost of Exclusion Based on Sexual Orientation, Gender Identity and Expression, and Sex Characteristics in the Labor Market in the Republic of North Macedonia”, Washington, DC: World Bank.

[21] Flores, A. et al. (2023), “The Economic Cost of Exclusion Based on Sexual Orientation, Gender Identity and Expression, and Sex Characteristics in the Labor Market in the Republic of Serbia”, Washington, DC: World Bank.

[29] Fluchtmann, J., V. van Veen and W. Adema (2023), “Fertility, employment and family policy: A cross-country panel analysis”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 299, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/326844f0-en.

[36] GBD (2019), Global Burden of Disease Collaborative Network. Global Burden of Disease Study 2019 (GBD 2019), Reference Life Table. Seattle, United States of America: Institute for Health Metrics and Evaluation (IHME), 2021.

[8] Guillemette, Y. et al. (2017), A revised approach to productivity convergence in long-term scenarios, OECD.

[3] Guillemette, Y. and D. Turner (2021), The long game: Fiscal outlooks to 2060 underline need for, OECD Economic Policy Papers, No. 29, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/a112307e-en.

[4] Guillemette, Y. and D. Turner (2018), The Long View: Scenarios for the World Economy to 2060, https://doi.org/10.1787/2226583X.

[33] Hoogendoorn, S., H. Oosterbeek and M. van Praag (2013), “The Impact of Gender Diversity on the Performance of Business Teams: Evidence from a Field Experiment”, Management Science, 59 (7), p. 1514-1528.

[34] Hoogendoorn, S. and M. van Praag (2018), “Ethnic Diversity and Team Performance: A Field Experiment”, Academy of Management Annual Meeting Proceedings.

[9] Jones, C. (2016), “The Facts of Economic Growth”, Handbook of Macroeconomics, Elsevier B.V., https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesmac.2016.03.002.

[24] LGBT Capital (2023), “Estimated LGBT Purchasing Power: LGBT-GDP - data as of year-end 2022 -”, https://www.lgbt-capital.com/docs/Estimated_LGBT-GDP_(table)_-_2023.pdf.

[15] Nyek, S. et al. (2019), The economic cost of LGBT stigma and discrimination in South Africa, UCLA Williams Institute.

[25] OECD (2023), “Health spending (indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/8643de7e-en.

[6] OECD (2023), Joining Forces for Gender Equality: What is Holding us Back?, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/67d48024-en.

[40] OECD (2023), “Pension spending (indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/a041f4ef-en.

[38] OECD (2023), “Public spending on incapacity (indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/f35b71ed-en.

[43] OECD (2023), “Public spending on labour markets (indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/911b8753-en.

[42] OECD (2023), “Public unemployment spending (indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/55557fd4-en.

[41] OECD (2023), “Social spending (Indicator)”, https://doi.org/10.1787/7497563b-en.

[7] OECD (2022), The Economic Case for More Gender Equality in Estonia, Gender Equality at Work, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/299d93b1-en.

[44] OECD (2021), “Preventing Harmful Alcohol Use”, OECD Health Policy Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/6e4b4ffb-en.

[32] OECD (2020), “All Hands In? Making Diversity Work for All”, https://doi.org/10.1787/efb14583-en.

[1] OECD (2020), Over the Rainbow? The Road to LGBTI Inclusion, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/8d2fd1a8-en.

[5] OECD (2020), Promoting an Age-Inclusive Workforce: Living, Learning and Earning Longer, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/59752153-en.

[18] Open for Business (2021), The economic case for LGBT+ inclusion in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE): Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Ukraine.

[19] Open for Business (2021), The economic case for LGBT+ inclusion in the Caribbean.

[37] Open for Business (2021), The Economic Case for LGBT+ Inclusion in Uzbekistan.

[11] Open for Business (2020), LGBT+ Inclusion and the UN Sustainable Development Goals.

[17] Open for Business (2020), The economic case for marriage equality in the Czech Republic.

[16] Open for Business (2019), The economic case for LGBT+ inclusion in Kenya.

[30] Prickett, K., A. Martin-Storey and R. Crosnoe (2015), “A Research Note on Time With Children in Different- and Same-Sex Two-Parent Families”, Demography, Vol. 52/3, pp. 905-918, https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-015-0385-2.

[23] Prudential (2017), “2016/2017 LGBT Financial Experience Research Report”, https://www.prudential.com/wps/wcm/connect/ba145fe5-88cf-48c3-ab67-6ab3cc5dba7a/PrudentialLGBT2016-2017.pdf?MOD=AJPERES&CVID=lYX8NZE&CVID=lYX8NZE.

[31] Rosenfeld, M. (2010), “Nontraditional families and childhood progress through school”, Demography, Vol. 47/3, pp. 755-775, https://doi.org/10.1353/dem.0.0112.

[12] Stonewall International (2016), LGBT Inclusion and the Sustainable Development Goals, https://www.stonewall.org.uk/resources/lgbt-inclusion-and-sustainable-development-goals.

[10] UN General Assembly (2015), Transforming Our World: The 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development, A/RES/70/1.

[35] World Health Organization (2001), Macroeconomic and Health: Investing in Health for Economic Development, Comission on Macroeconomics and Health. Prepared for the World Health Organization.

A life-cycle approach recognises that both the share of self-identified LGBTI+ individuals and the extent of their labour market disparities differ by sex and cohort. However, it is not a realistic method as it concomitantly assumes that these shares and disparities change as individuals in each group age. For instance, if, as detailed in Table 4.1, AFAB LGBTI+ individuals aged 20 in 2024 experience a 12.8% lower labour productivity than their cisgender straight peers, the life-cycle approach presumes that this gap will have disappeared as they age to 56 by the year 2060 (while the share of LGBTI+ individuals among the AFAB population aged 55-74 will then be equal to 4.4%, not 28% as it is the case for the AFAB population aged 15-34 in 2024). This assumption is at odd with Chapter 2. Notably, according to Chapter 2, the rising proportion of young adults identifying as LGBTI+ is not driven by an age effect which would entail that, for younger generations, self-identifying as LGBTI+ is a fad that ceases once they grow older.

Despite its lack of realism, we analyse the economic consequences of closing labour market gaps for LGBTI+ individuals under the life-cycle approach. Not surprisingly, the economic benefits of achieving LGBTI+ equality are the lowest under this approach. Indeed, this method projects a decrease in the proportion of self-identified individuals within the total population as the younger cohorts age, leading to a decline in the extent of labour market disparities for LGBTI+ individuals in the total population.

Still the economic benefits of addressing the unexplained labour market disparities affecting LGBTI+ individuals would remain significant under a life-cycle approach (Annex Figure 4.A.1). Under this approach, the GDP is projected to increase by 1.2%, 1.2%, and 1.1% of the baseline GDP by 2030, 2040, and 2050, respectively. These projections assume that the United States achieves LGBTI+ equality by these respective time horizons.

Under the life-cycle approach, attaining LGBTI+ equality by 2030 would result in an average annual increase in GDP of approximately 0.2%, which amounts to 10% of the average annual US GDP growth observed between 2013 and 2023. However, delaying the achievement of LGBTI+ equality would yield reduced economic benefits when translated in yearly GDP gains. The average annual increase in GDP would be equal to 0.07% if the target year is 2040, and to 0.04% if the target year is 2050.

Notes

← 1. More precisely:

  • AtCS*NtCS=

A18-34,tAMAB,CS*N18-34, tAMAB,CS+A35-54,tAMAB,CS*N35-54, tAMAB,CS+A55-74,tAMAB,CS*N55-74, tAMAB,CS

+A18-34,tAFAB,CS*N18-34, tAFAB,CS+A35-54,tAFAB,CS*N35-54, tAFAB,CS+A55-74,tAFAB,CS*N55-74, tAFAB,CS;

  • AtLGBTI+*NtLGBTI+=

A18-34,tAMAB,LGBTI+*N18-34, tAMAB,LGBTI++A35-54,tAMAB,LGBTI+*N35-54, tAMAB,LGBTI++A55-74,tAMAB,LGBTI+*N55-74, tAMAB,LGBTI+

+A18-34,tAFAB,LGBTI+*N18-34, tAFAB,LGBTI++A35-54,tAFAB,LGBTI+*N35-54, tAFAB,LGBTI++A55-74,tAFAB,LGBTI+*N55-74, tAFAB,LGBTI+.

← 2. Results available upon request.

← 3. See: (OECD, 2023[42]; OECD, 2023[43]; OECD, 2023[40]; OECD, 2023[41])

← 4. In a 2001 study, Christopher Banks aimed to calculate the aggregate economic costs of health disparities among lesbian, gay, and bisexual individuals in Canada (Banks, 2001[39]). His analysis focused on lost productivity from morbidity and premature mortality, direct healthcare expenditures, and other costs like prevention. Assuming that 5% to 10% of the Canadian population identified as LGB, he estimated the total economic burden of increased health conditions attributable to homophobia for five health conditions. These estimates were USD 695 million to USD 823 million for suicide, USD 281 million to USD 623 million for smoking-related issues, USD 290 million to USD 4.1 billion for alcohol abuse, USD 119 million to USD 221 million for illicit drug use, and USD 540 million to USD 2.3 billion for depression, all reported in Canadian dollars of the time (2001).

← 5. Including these additional health disparities in the analysis could significantly increase the aggregate economic and well-being costs. For instance, it is estimated that the GDP of the United States is reduced by nearly 1.9% due to the impact of diseases caused by alcohol consumption on life expectancy, health expenditure, employment, and productivity (OECD, 2021[44]).

← 6. Years lived with a disability (YLD) are valued based on the public’s perceptions about the severity of the health condition, while years of life lost (YLL) are calculated for someone with a disease by subtracting the age at death from a standard life expectancy value, defined as the lowest death rate for an age group across countries.

Legal and rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD 2024

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at https://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.